Grandstand platforms

A cursory glance at the myriad apps and websites that clutter our online lives would suggest rich competition. In reality, online diversity is in decline.

The online economy’s lack of diversity can be seen most clearly in technology itself, where a power disparity has grown in the last decade, leaving the web in the control of fewer and fewer. Google Search makes up 92% of all web searches worldwide. Its browser, Chrome, which defaults to Google Search, is used by nearly two thirds of users worldwide.

Source: StatCounter Global Stats – Search Engine Market Share

Media investment analysis firm Ebiquity found that nearly half of all advertising spend is now digital, with Google, Meta (formerly Facebook) and Amazon single-handedly collecting nearly three quarters of digital advertising money globally in 2021.

Further to that, recent research examining global competition across all industries over the last decade finds that across all industries, a small number of companies (as represented by the domains they control) account for an ever-increasing share of the total online attention.

By its very nature, this emerging monopoly is difficult to control and regulate. When a US judge found that the Federal Trade Commission’s antitrust case against Facebook lacked evidence, it became clear that regulators were struggling with the challenge of even defining what type of business platforms such as Facebook are in, let alone measure and prove dominance or lack thereof in that domain.

Regulators across the largest global markets are continuing to look for ways to constrain platforms: the EU’s Digital Markets Act aims to target “gatekeeper” platforms, while in the US, Congress continues to debate the American Choice and Innovation Online Act, which seeks to stop the largest players from limiting competition.

A shift in competition

The economic law of diminishing returns, relied on for centuries as a handbrake on monopolies arising organically in new industries, no longer applies in the online context. The familiar pattern of a leading company or brand existing alongside challengers and niche brands (think Coke, Pepsi and Dr. Pepper) in a market oligopoly, has not migrated online.

In the last century acquisitions, mergers and implosions were rife, but oligopolies where a few major players carved up a market were common. This century, the digitisation of the economy removed much of the fundamental ‘friction’ in business and with it many of the natural barriers to monopoly.

Digital technology adoption across all industries has unleashed a new set of economic forces including increasing returns, interoperability, network effects and switching costs, that together can be referred to as ‘Online Gravity’.

Is technology a malevolent force contributing to the growth of monopolies or is it a benign wellspring of innovation and healthy competition

Online software companies see the marginal cost of attracting additional customers go down, not up, as market share increases. In the business-to-business market, companies build services into their “stack” and an entire ecosystem based on interoperability grows around them. Multi-sided marketplaces such as Airbnb offer greater utility to both hosts and guests by tapping a larger network. And when staff become adept at using an enterprise software system such as SAP, no-one wants to relearn a rival system, nor the time cost that comes with it.

These new rules of platform economics mean many sectors are now characterised by one very large and dominant leader and much smaller niche players.  

And so there’s a conundrum. Is technology a malevolent force contributing to the growth of monopolies or is it a benign wellspring of innovation and healthy competition? The answer is it’s both – depending on how you look at things.

The paradox of diversity

With its low barriers to entry, the frictionless online world is often thought of and portrayed as intensely competitive with a constant stream of innovation arising from an army of basement entrepreneurs and increasingly patient investors willing to back them. And yes, that is true. But alongside sit platforms that are becoming the largest companies in history — many of which dominate their corners of the world. 

Most platforms are not malevolent forces, but they do have some unintended consequences: they work like pine trees, dropping needles in a wide arc around where they stand, preventing new shoots emerging in their space. And there is evidence that that arc around established companies worldwide is growing .

Around half the websites that began in 2005 are still around more than 15 years later. But since then, fewer and fewer websites have survived beyond their first few years. Over 90% of the websites that launched in 2018 failed within two years.

Research published last year examining the global “infant survival rates” of newborn enterprises over the last decade found them to be in long-term decline. Links in social media as a measure of whether an enterprise was “alive” after its first appearance found that, while almost 40% of those born in 2006 were active five years on, only a little over 3% of those born in 2015 are active today.

Online diversity
Evolution of diversity and dominance of companies in online activity. Credit: Paul X. McCarthy et. al.

This is partly due to the power of tech giants to acquire or bundle features of early stage innovators into their platforms, often at no cost. Microsoft famously made its web browser Internet Explorer the default for all pre-installed Windows PCs worldwide and incorporated web-server software into its dominant operating system, spelling an early death for web pioneer Netscape. 

Many recent innovations in social media pioneered by Snapchat (ephemeral messaging), TikTok and, before it, Twitter’s Vine (short videos) have since been incorporated as new features into Instagram Stories and Instagram Reels. 

Rethinking monopoly

The regulation of online platforms and the companies that operate them present some special challenges for governments due to their scale and global nature. The platforms are naturally global, yet the business of government itself and its related functions — of promoting a level playing field for businesses, collecting tax and ensuring citizen privacy is protected — is rarely global. Moves are afoot on this front, with the OECD coordinating a plan for new international taxation rules among 130 countries.

US Federal Trade Commission Chair Lina Khan has paved the way for a rethink of monopolies and the need to look beyond pricing and market share in her earlier work as an academic. In Khan’s words: “The long-term interests of consumers include product quality, variety and innovation — factors best promoted through both a robust competitive process and open markets.”

online
In less than a decade, Google on the other hand has overtaken the US Government in mentions in English language books. Credit: Online Gravity.

Understanding the future of competition in this new economy also requires making an important distinction between structural and functional competition. 

For example, Facebook claims many of its users also use other services such as YouTube and Twitter. But simply because they share users or even advertisers doesn’t necessarily mean they are in direct competition. 

Google and Facebook do compete for consumer advertising revenue but in the same way that Ferrari competes with, say, Tesla or Hyundai for a share of the broad automotive pie. Many Ferrari drivers also own other cars, such as family sedans or SUVs manufactured by other companies, but it doesn’t mean these companies compete in any meaningful way with Ferrari. They are structurally similar (all in the automotive industry, all with four wheels etc) but functionally worlds apart (off-road and family transport versus sports car).

The clear evidence that economic structural diversity is in long-term decline is somewhat balanced by analysis that shows clear, continued growth in functional diversity.

Technology continues to support the emergence of new categories of applications (such as ephemeral social messaging), services (online movies) and products (electric vehicles) and each one goes through a now-predictable cycle of explosive growth, competition and dominance by a leading company.

Google and Facebook do compete for consumer advertising revenue but in the same way that Ferrari competes with, say, Tesla or Hyundai for a share of the broad automotive pie.

While it’s important to find ways of regulating global technology platforms, it’s perhaps equally if not more important to promote innovation through the cycle of ongoing functional diversity – to return to the platforms-as-pine-trees analogy, encouraging new species of trees to grow in new areas.  


Read also: Too easy


To date, most of the world’s largest global technology giants have emerged from the US or China. But with increasingly global venture capital investments, we’re starting to see a new wave of global tech giants emerge from centres such as London (Checkout.com), Stockholm (Klarna) and Sydney (Canva).

Despite the rise of trade protectionism, the economics of online gravity are here to stay, so our best economic bet is to ensure more tech-enabled ecosystems flourish in a greater range of communities worldwide. National digital infrastructure is going to become more important to economic development and productivity. And governments and regulators will need to get better at measuring and promoting the benefits that flow from greater global economic diversity.

online
Tech Giants Apple & Microsoft jostle for the title of the largest US Company. Here an aerial view of Apple Park is seen in Cupertino, California, United States on October 28, 2021. Credit: Tayfun CoÅkun / Anadolu Agency / Getty

Paul McCarthy’s 2015 book Online Gravity explains how technology is rebooting economics worldwide.

This article was published in partnership with 360info.org

Please login to favourite this article.